K.Patelis on Mon, 22 Mar 1999 19:55:42 +0100 (CET) |
[Date Prev] [Date Next] [Thread Prev] [Thread Next] [Date Index] [Thread Index]
<nettime> political economy of Internet [1/2] |
Dear All, I forward to you a article written sometime ago published in J.Curran (eds) (1999)Media Organisations Arnold (they have copyright over this - the joys of publishing in academia!) I assume I will get the normal "we are beyond the Californian Ideology" responce, this articles clearly understands so spare me! Hope you like it Korinna Patelis ----------------------- THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF THE INTERNET The development of the Internet in the West was attended by a hyped ideology that sees in the Internet the cure for a number of ills besetting contemporary society: Internet-philia. This hegemonic approach to the changes the Internet impregnates extends to all aspects of life, from academia to finance, to politics. It has essentially framed the way we perceive and talk about the Net, marginalising any approach that does not subscribe to the rosy technological deterministic view of our inevitable free-market future. Though some have pointed to the metaphysical, speculative and futuristic nature of the discussions involved (Barbrook 1996, Hacker 1996, Krocker 1996, Sardar 1996, Schuler 1998, Schudson 1998), the lack of systematic critique and the holistic nature of the dogma in question has led to an unprecedented move towards deregulation in communication and to the uncritical introduction of e-commerce on-line. The Internet has become a symbol for global free-market capitalism. In opposition to the existing paradigm, this article will show that socio-economico-political factors determine on-line communication and largely control the future of the Internet. Consequently, the regulation of Internet related industries is of paramount importance, if the Internet is to have any public service function. Internetphilia has been announcing the inevitable arrival of a whole new era, one whose features are dramatically different, whose qualities and mechanisms cannot be understood with past methods of analysis. It constantly perpetuates the notion of a clear break with the past. The motor engine of such newness is purely technological; it is a change in essence, a qualitative change ( Kahin & Nessson 1997:vii) which in turn installs a new mode of producing, distributing and consuming information. The underlying theme is the transition from analogue to digital information; the ability to store information in combinations of one and zero is the messiah of the new era (Negroponte 1995:11-20)(Al Gore 1994). The basic qualities possessed by digital technology are newness and dynamism. Everything is new , everything is in constant fast movement. What is new today will be old tomorrow because the digital injects all aspects of society with dynamism. Dynamism destroys power by making it temporary . Consequently everything will be transformed continuously, nothing will be stale, no structures will prevail. No knowledge will be diachronic, no policy definite, no question permanent; therefore our understanding of knowledge has to change. The digitalisation of technology is causing changes in society as a whole, changes which cannot be understood, addressed, or dealt with if a new philosophy is not installed. The constant reference to time and the up-to-dateness of knowledge labels those critical of technopia "anachronistic", their understanding of the technological change "poor", they are "digitally homeless" (Negroponte 1995:7). Through this process alternative perspectives are silenced and Internet-philic authors assume the position of cyber-visionaries. Internetphilia's strength lies in its ability to present itself as the messiah of the digital era. And it is only by assuming this cyber-elite position that it proceeds to found its faith in the Internet. Internetphilia advocates that Internet communication will enhance freedom . Freedom is what the virtual frontier stands for; the value that is prioritised over any other. However, the freedom in question is the negative idea of freedom, meaning freedom from external restrictions - as opposed to a positive idea of freedom as freedom to (Berlin 1969 ). Internetphilia is fixated upon the idea that the Internet is free; a sovereign entity. What is constantly implied is that the Internet by virtue of being free is constituted in the realm of virtual freedom, above existing relations, above society. Freedom from reality is what virtuality in the age of the Internet stands for, and freedom from reality means freedom from any social, economic or political micro or macro process, culture included. The Internet substitutes for the structured confined system of corrupt representative democracy an inherently free paradigm for direct democracy. To be a Netizen and participate in this de-localised agora is natural right in the digital world; one free from territoriality and social constraints. Freedom to act in the Internet means freedom to speak. Freedom of expression - virtually the symbol of cyber-freedom - is what Netizens campaign for, It is further maintained that the Internet is global (Gore 1994a:7), because it annuls distance and thus removes the limitations of geography (Negroponte 1995:165), (Johnson & Post 1997:6) transforming the geopolitics of information, i.e. the unequal access to information across the globe due to geographical location, (Negroponte 1996a) . Geography is redundant as is also geo-power. Consequently, the Internet will empower individuals inhabiting the social margins and the institutions and countries of the socio-economic periphery (Poster 1995) (Turckle 1995) (Johnson & Post 1997). It will subvert the current power structure by transforming citizens across the globe from orthodox media couch-potatoes to active producers of on-line information (Goodwin 1996). Such empowerment is further enabled by the fact that technically the Internet is decentralised, it has no centre and thus cannot be technically controlled (Negroponte 1995; Johnson and Post 1997; Froomkin 1997; Gates 1996; Volkmer 1996; Barret 1996; Caruso 1996; Schwartz 1997); not to mention that the sheer volume of information passing through makes it impossible to exercise any control over it (Johnson & Post 1997). The idea is that the technical impossibility of regulation and control cripple nation-state power (Carruso 1996:57). This and Internetphilia's concern with individual freedom mean that Internetphilia is inherently anti-statist (Poster 1995, Browning 1996, 1998, Kline & Burstein 1996, Rodrigues 1997, Chapman 1995, Gidary 1996, Barlow 1996, Heileman 1996, Steele 1996, Economist 1997a, Negroponte 1996, Economist 1996b, Volkmer 1996, Kahin 1997, Abrams 1997, Johnson & Post 1997, Rapp 1997, Abraham 1997, Froomkin 1997, Neuman, Mc Knight & Solomon 1997). The state is portrayed as an inefficient anachronism, a bureaucratic enemy of freedom, its presence unnecessary for the proper functioning of the Internet . The state loses its legitimacy in the on-line world (Johnson & Post 1997:10); it ought and will slowly wither away as cyberspace becomes wider and wider (Negroponte 1995:230, Barlow 1996a). The above faith in the Internet is shared by Internetphilia's advocates who come from all aspects of life and vary in their focus. In academia and journalism one can, firstly, distinguish a liberal-populist approach concerned with individual freedom and the Internet as the market place of ideas (Negroponte 1995, Froomkin 1997, Dyson 1998); the most recent advocates of such an approach are market determinists; (Solomon 1997, Huber 1997, Economist 1997, Schwarz 1997, Barlow 1997, Kahin 1997, Rosseto 1997:244, Tapshot 1996). Second, one also finds a more postmodernist approach analysing how Internet communication frees the subject from the ontological curse of modernity (Poster 1995, Turckle 1995, Reid 1996, Renan 1996). In politics, the Clinton administration in the U.S. and the Bangeman approach in the E.U have been the key proponents of the liberalisation of communication in the name of convergence (Clinton Administration 1993, 1995, 1997, Clinton 1992, 1998, Gore, 1993, 1994, 1994a, Bangeman 1997, Bangeman 1997a, KPMG 1996 Papas 1997:5 CEC 1994:8,15, CEC 1997). In business too, the exploitation of the digital moment has been inevitable ( Gates 1996, Henning 1997, Hammond 1996). Internetphilia articulates in two ways. Though these are not neatly separated, the first, whose central tenets are analysed above, refuses to accept that there is private property in the on-line world line (Barlow 1996:172, Negroponte 1995:59) or that property affects the on-line world (Turckle 1995). The Internet is constructed as an inherently anarchic system, juxtaposed to the current property system. Internetphilia's second articulation, currently hegemonic, shares the features outlined above, but is also characterised by a celebration of the existing private property system, a market determinism which, with the announcement of convergence, is naturalised as the only way for the future of public policy. In short the Internet and the market are presented as essentially similar entities, inseparable and self-regulatory. Internetphilia's second articulation developed in response to the Internet's incipient commercialisation. The Internet was now viewed as commercialised : "it has gone corporate", mainstream (Schwartz 1997:15, Economist 1996, Lorh 1994, Noam 1997, Andrews 1994, Hudson 1997:11-37, Miller 1996:23-24, Henning 1997:17-18, Sassen 1997). In the face of such commercialisation any claim that the Net transcends material relations was no longer sustainable. In replacement of such a claim came a celebration; a bold assertion/approach which exclusively constitutes the way in which the Internet and private property are discussed, namely, that the Internet gives rise to a whole new financial environment, a new economy. It is a "digital economy" based on abundance rather than scarcity; a market where supply equals demand and prices are set at the lowest optimum level; where oligopolies are avoided owing to low market-entry costs; where market dysfunctions are history and diversity is guaranteed. This market is a producer and consumer paradise. Its hallmark is dynamic competition (Gilder 1996:5). In the world of bits, there is no packaging, there is no distribution (they are automatic). Marginal costs are abolished, in consequence of which economies of scale no longer yield a competitive advantage. Whereas differential pricing is difficult in an atom economy, it is a matter of an extra click in the bit-economy. Such characteristics lead to an increase in network efficiency. This is the market driven by demand. For, if the necessary condition for market efficiency is that the marginal willingness to pay equal marginal cost (Varian 1996, Negroponte 1997), price on the Net equals marginal willingness to pay. In other words, demand sets prices and, instead of scarcity of supply the Web economy "exhibits a scarcity of demand" (Schwartz 1997:2). Demand can finally get its revenge, it can obtain the power it always deserved, for this is the market of the people (Negroponte 1997a: 112). In other words, traditional market conditions that can lead to exploitation are based on scarcity. If the Internet is the perfect market, then capitalism is the perfect system, for no inequalities will be produced (Geer 1996:24). In B. Gate's words Capitalism, demonstrably the greatest of the constructed economic systems, has in the past decade clearly proved its advantages over the alternative systems, As the Internet evolves into its broadband, global interactive network, those advantages will be magnified. Product and service providers will see what buyers want a lot more efficiently than ever before and consumers will buy more efficiently. I think Adam Smith would be pleased (Gates 1996) If the market cannot be dominated, no company can have increasingly large profits (Stol 1996:283) and attempts to colonise cyberspace are doomed to fail (Bloomberg 1997, Kantor 1998, Stol 1996:282). Through the notion of the new economy, the market and the Internet are constructed as essentially similar entities; the Internet bears a fundamental resemblance to the market. Indeed, it becomes a metaphor for it. As Kahin puts it Then again, the market itself has never moved this fast. Within a growing investment community, the Internet is seen not only as the once and future NII, but as a vast frontier for innovationand enterprise. It is at once physical, logical and institutional , an organic mesh of unfathomable richness and vitality. It bears an eerie resemblance to the marketplace itself-which, with the coming of the electronic commerce, it promises to electrify in a reciprocal embrace ( Kahin 1997: 184) Given the virtues of the new economy, why deprive the world of the opportunity for the Internet to install an environment of competition and act as a democratiser in other areas of economic activity apart from communication? In setting up this argument Internet-philia places e-commerce at the center of the agenda. If the Internet is an economy of abundance, then the buying and selling of goods other than communication should not jeopardise e-communication (Hagel & Amstrong 1997:16). Gradually, the Internet is not defined solely as a communications medium, but also as a delivery platform, an infrastructure/technology on which many applications can be run as the users fancy (Solomon 1998, Lehr 1998). Given the prospect of using the Net for both e-commerce and e-communication, as well as any other application, how does one regulate it? And in the face of such a perfect digital economy, why should one regulate it? The promises of the new economy have strengthened the anti-statist basis of Internetphilia. The anti-statist campaign launched for the CDA is accompanied by a hegemonic conviction that the Internet is not, cannot and should not be regulated. The theme which facilitates Internetphilia's quest for minimum regulation and the free market is convergence. What is put forth is that telecoms, a liberalised industry, and broadcasting, more or less regulated, are converging into one technology. It is not sound to have two different regulatory paradigms for the same technology. A liberalised paradigm is better able to deal with the ever mutating technological change as well as with the multi-functional nature of the Net. In short if different applications are to co-habit online than only a liberalised regulatory regime can deal with them. In public policy, convergence is the core of Internetphilia's second articulation. Internetphilia's two articulations are very similar: for the first, a distinction between production and consumption online does not exist. For the latter, a distinction between production and consumption online can be made, but it is insignificant since the power relationship between the two has been subverted by the perfect market. The backlash There is a tendency to perceive of Internetphilia as an ideology that is now going through a backlash, the expression of the Internet's adolescence, a hype cured by the medium's maturation (Naom 1997, Sassen 1997, Bettig 1997, Hudson 1997). Such an approach is misleading. Firstly, it does not make any chronological sense since Internetphilic literature is on the increase. Secondly, it is itself Internetphilic since it reflects the notion of constant change. Thirdly, it underestimates the centrality of Internetphilia's second articulation for the business world. The Internet has become virgin economic territory for every entrepreneur. Fourthly, it is blind to the fact that public policies, echoing and promoting the above central claims, are being instituted and implemented at the same time as authors are speaking of a backlash. Internetphilia differs from the hyped ideologies that attended the rise of cable TV, for example, in that it involves/brings about dramatic policy changes in the regulation of communications technologies: the Telecommunications Act of 1996, the Green Paper on Convergence are unprecedented moves towards deregulation in the history of mass communication. The backlash scenario undermines how central public policy has been in promoting the Internetphilic agenda. The neoliberal policy framework set by Internetphilia in the name of technological determinism has urged governments across the world to adopt a U.S.-based liberal framework for the regulation of e-communication. Any sporadic backlash against such an agenda has been labeled anachronistic or protectionist. A whole neoliberal way of perceiving of communication has been dictated in the name of technology. The Internet's symbolic power in promoting state-capitalist development and resurrecting bankrupt free- market policy is a power on the increase. With the arrival of e-commerce such power has consequences that extend to areas other than communication. There is no backlash against the Internet's symbolic power. Finally, the notion of a backlash does not recognise how central the introduction of e-commerce is in affecting the whole nature of the Internet. E-commerce alters the function of the Internet from a communication medium to a delivery platform. Its terrestrial equivalent would be to introduce 500 new TV shopping channels and argue that this will not affect the function of TV. The introduction of e-commerce on-line needs to be criticised. It has not been sufficiently criticised because backlash and criticism have one more shortcoming. They reduce all objections to access, and hence an 'info-rich and info-poor' analysis stands as the only opposition to Internetphilia (Bettig 1997, Sussman 1997:171). Though access is an important issue, centering on access for critique leaves the impression that it is the lack of infrastructure and access that are stifling the digital democracy. But such a standpoint reflects the Internetphilic tenets which should be overcome. The uneven spread of the Internet's development is recognised in OECD reports, EU official documents, global information infrastructure documents, etc. An access-centered critique is formalist, it makes no normative claims and defends no ideal function for the Internet, it merely restates that the individual should have access to the Internet. There is no discussion of Internet content. The content could be anything. To produce a fruitful critique one has to comprehend that it is not Internetphilia's level of euphoria that is problematic, it is not that the correct questions have been set and Internetphilia merely gives the wrong answers. It is that the questions are wrong. What does demand for Internet access mean? Access to what? And access for what purpose? Why should the advocators of free-market capitalism be given the right to hegemonise a medium, and define its whole nature? Why is the market more inherently similar to the Net than to the radio? Why should e-commerce and e-communication co-exist - even if compatible? Do we put stores in our schools though we may accept that this would not intervene in the learning process? Why is it taken for granted that the ideal is an Internet the uses of which are decided by the individual? And who has accepted a priori that there is a sovereign entity such as the abstract individual to determine such access? Internetphilia's philosophical basis can be criticised on the same grounds as many neo-liberal dogmas: a faith in the abstract individual (Marx 1968:29), an unfounded conviction that the individual is detached from the social, that it is sovereign (Sandel 1982, Taylor 1990, Walzer 1983, MacIntyre 1981, 1988, 1990). Also a belief in negative liberty founded upon the tautology that man, being born free, ought to be free. In addition, it can be argued that Internetphilia is a technological deterministic dogma. It can also be argued that it naturalises and reifies the market and the Net. Furthermore, Internetphilia exhibits an unjustified faith in direct democracy. It is also blind to the fact that scarcity is a not a technologically dictated phenomenon but an economic reality. Thus, no matter what the technology in question, there is no such thing as an economy of abundance, since economic goods are by definition scarce. Continuity in the digital world The way in which we perceive of the questions central to understanding e-communication has drastically to change. To do so it is necessary to mend the carefully constructed ruptures with the past and posit "power" as a central concept in our understanding of the Internet. Internetphilia dislocates the Internet from economic, historical and social conditions, leaving its audience confident that knowledge of the virtual world does not assume an understanding of such conditions. It establishes an analytic framework marked by virtual communication essentialism, a tendency to describe and analyse the Internet in a historical, institutional and above all economic vacuum, the central assertion being that even if there is an Internet economy such an economy is novel and different. This in turn skillfully renders concerns related to financial inequality, public function and pluralism redundant. In order, then, that any paradigmatic shift be possible, it is imperative that it be attended by an understanding of on-line communication as physically located within current socio-economic power structures and therefore as framed by material factors. The current picture of the Internet is in striking contrast to Internetphilic claims. Inequalities in Internet development and the nature of the development in question mirror rather than subvert state-capitalist power structures. This is no surprise given that there has been no attempt to develop the Internet in any other fashion. The Internet did not develop in a economic vacuum, it is part of a wider context and economic environment. As a communication medium it is enabled by a combination of technologies the production of which has been commodified for at least one decade, the infocommunication sector valued at 1.3 trillion (Herman and Mc Chesney 1998). Estimates of the Internet's participation in this economy vary. According to Forester Research, Internet activity generated revenue of over $2.2 billion in 1995; ActivMedia claims that reported online revenues reached 21.4 billion in 1997, Forester's estimate is $14,4 billion in the 1997. Estimates of what revenue the Internet will be generating by 2001 vary from Forrester's 45.4 billion dollars (Forrester 1995) to B.Gates own prediction of 13-15 billion by 2001 (Wheelwright G. 1996: 9); ActiveMedia projects this figure to 1.234 billion in 2002. Thus the Internet is a commodified medium, the exchange value of online communication is prioritised over its other values. There are four main ways in which such prioritisation takes place, each generating significant revenues. First, the commodification of access: the internet service provision market is now worth 8.4 billion dollars (AOL alone has 13 million subscribers and is worth 2 billion dollars). Second, the commodification of Internet navigation tools and search engines (Yahoo's revenues alone where $30, 206,00 in the first quarter of 1998). Third, advertising: Web advertising revenue grew by 28% to 169.8 million in the third quarter of 1997 (Cowles/Simbanet 1997). For the sake of clarity the Internet economy can be divided into infrastructure and content as shown in Figure 1. Such a distinction (though false) firstly makes it clear that the Internet is physically located; this means its function is totally dependent upon Internet infrastructure. The two parts of the Internet economy exist in a hierarchy, without the infrastructure there can be no online activity or content (OECD 1997). Internet infrastructure is the production and distribution of the online world, distribution being of paramount importance. Connectivity, bandwidth and hardware are for the Internet what transmission reception, clearness and T.V. sets are for television broadcasting; and they are scarce. Speed stability and security are factors that make up connectivity. The infrastructure/content distinction moreover routes e-communication into older industries, old fashioned markets with well established players. This has to be reflected back to the notion of an 'economic break with the past'. Routing Internet industries into older industries undermines the notion of a totally "new economy", a virgin market, uncontaminated by the monopolies of old-media, where "everybody gets to have a go"; the Internet is inevitably determined by older economies and industries. Figure 1:The Internet Economy THE CONTENT Broadcasters, Web-casters, on-line content providers, Web-site designers, database providers, advertisers, governments, on-line users? THE INFRASTRUTURE Search Engines, Navigation Tools, ISP's Hardware, Software & Server Industries Public Telecommunication Operators There is, of course, convergence in the Internet economy. A more accurate term for describing this phenomenon is vertigal integration. ISP's are being bought by telecoms companies, search engines are launching joint ventures with telecoms and ISP's (MCI & YAHOO), broadcasters & telecoms (Line-One: the joint venture of BT and News Corp). Since infrastructure determines content, vertical integration or synergies are instigated and benefit companies that are part of the Internet infrastructure; It is precicely because infrastructure determines content that the Internet cannot be said to be hyper-geographical or hyper-economical. There is an Internet architecture, a geo-economy that determines e-activity. Such a geo-economy constitutes a series of inequalities which not only determine who uses the Internet but above all the way in which the Internet is used. All connections to the Internet do not cost the same, are not of the same speed or bandwidth; all uses of the Internet are not growing at the same speed, all subscriptions do not allow the same activity, all content does not have the same chance of being viewed. [End of 1/2] --- # distributed via nettime-l : no commercial use without permission # <nettime> is a closed moderated mailinglist for net criticism, # collaborative text filtering and cultural politics of the nets # more info: majordomo@desk.nl and "info nettime-l" in the msg body # URL: http://www.desk.nl/~nettime/ contact: nettime-owner@desk.nl